- Zur Macht-Diskusion..... - --- ELLI ---, 15.07.2002, 15:16
Zur Macht-Diskusion.....
Ich habe es leider noch nicht gelesen, könnte aber interessant sein.
------------------------------------------------------
<font face="Verdana" size="1" color="#002864">http://www.mises.org/fullstory.asp?control=996</font>
<font face="Verdana" color="#002864" size="5"><strong>Calhoun's Cause: Free
Trade</strong></font>
<font size="4">by Thomas J. DiLorenzo</font>
<font size="2">[Posted July 15, 2002]</font>
<font size="3">[img][/img] In
<em>The
Essential Calhoun</em> (<em>TEC</em>), editor Clyde Wilson commented that
"it is curious how ignorant contemporary advocates of free markets are of
tariff struggles in nineteenth-century America." </font>
<font size="3">There is much truth in this statement, since most advocates of
free markets seem to be more interested in pure economic theory than in history.
Understanding the momentous political struggles over tariffs in 19th-century
America can greatly improve our understanding of free trade in particular and of
American economic history in general--especially the history of the War Between
the States.</font>
<font size="3">Any such endeavor must start with the free-trade writings of
South Carolinian John C. Calhoun, who served as U.S. senator, secretary of war,
secretary of state, and vice president of the United States during a 40-year
public career (1810-1850). </font>
<font size="3">Calhoun made dozens of speeches and wrote many letters on the
issue of free trade, which he viewed as nothing less than the source of
civilization itself. In a March 24, 1845, letter to Richard Cobden and
William Bright of the Manchester, England, Anti-Corn League, he wrote: "I
regard free trade, as involving considerations far higher, than mere commercial
advantages, as great as they are. It is, in my opinion, emphatically the
cause of civilization and peace" (<em>TEC</em>, p. 218). </font>
<font size="3">Ludwig von Mises echoed this sentiment in <em>Human
Action</em> (scholar’s edition, p. 827) when he wrote that</font>
<blockquote style="MARGIN-RIGHT: 0px">
<font size="3">"What distinguishes man from animals is the insight
into the advantages that can be derived from cooperation under the division of
labor. Man curbs his innate instinct of aggression in order to cooperate
with other human beings. The more he wants to improve his material well
being, the more he must expand the system of the division of labor."</font>
[/i]
<font size="3">And, of course, international trade is an indispensable means
of doing so.</font>
<font size="3">A contemporary of Calhoun's, French political economist
Frederic Bastiat, stressed this same theme when he said that"if goods
can’t cross borders armies will." Bastiat equated protectionism with
legalized plunder, which in his eyes was the same as communism (see his essay
"Protectionism and
Communism" in <em>Selected Essays on Political Economy</em>).</font>
<font size="3">It is important to understand that in 19th-century America,
the tariff was the chief source of federal revenue; there were no income, social
security, or capital gains taxes. Consequently, the great political
struggle between the Jeffersonians and the Hamiltonians over the appropriate
size and scope of the central government often centered on the issue of the
tariff. To the advocates of centralized governmental power (the Federalists,
then the Whigs, and later the Republican Party of Lincoln), the protectionist
tariff was not only a means of protecting politically favored industries from
competition; it was the potential economic lifeblood of big government.</font>
<font size="3">Calhoun understood this better than anyone, and, since he
considered himself to be a political heir of Jefferson's, he spent a quarter of
a century in fierce opposition to protectionist tariffs. He knew that the
power to tax could become the power to destroy and was in some ways the American
Bastiat. (Interestingly, Bastiat's first American translator was a constituent
of Calhoun's, Louisa S. McCord of Columbia, South Carolina.) Calhoun’s
arguments in defense of free trade were economic, political, and constitutional.</font>
<font size="3">Calhoun understood that while all consumers would be burdened
by protectionist tariffs, the manufacturing North would enjoy a net benefit at
the expense of the agricultural and export-dependent South, since protection
enabled it to raise the prices of the goods it sold. In a September 1828 letter
to Micah Sterling, he wrote that"Almost every man to the North, let his
employment be what it may... hopes to receive more from the Tariff by the
increased price of his labour, or his property than what he pays in duties, as a
consumer" (<em>TEC</em>, p. 190).</font>
<font size="3">He also recognized the fundamental economic fact that
restricting imports with protectionism will eventually restrict a country’s
exports as well by reducing the wealth of that country’s trading partners.
"During the eight years of high duties [1824-1832], the increase of our
foreign commerce, and of our tonnage... was almost entirely arrested; and..
. the exports of domestic manufactures actually fell off" (<em>TEC</em>, p.
192). He thus considered protectionism to be a form of economic"warfare"
against export-related industries, primarily lumber, fisheries, agriculture, and
shipping.</font>
<font size="3">Calhoun explained what contemporary economists refer to as the
"optimal tariff," which is a variant of the Laffer Curve idea:</font>
<font size="3">"On all articles on which duties can be imposed, there is
a point in the rate of duties which may be called the maximum point of
revenue--that is, a point at which the greatest amount of revenue would be
raised. If it be elevated above that, the importation of the article would
fall off more rapidly than the duty would be raised; and, if depressed below
it, the reverse effect would follow: that is, the duty would decrease more
rapidly than the importation would increase. If the duty be raised above that
point, it is manifest that all the intermediate space between the maximum
point and that to which it may be raised, would be purely protective, and not
for revenue." (<em>TEC</em>, p. 195)</font>
<font size="3">Unlike many supply-side economists, however, Calhoun did not
believe that maximizing government revenue was"optimal" or even
desirable. It must first be proved that the expenditures to be financed with the
higher tariff revenues are constitutional, he said. During the 1824-1832
high-tariff period, the federal budget surplus"led to the vast expansion
of the currency... from which have succeeded so many disasters. It was that
which wrecked the currency, overthrew the... entire machinery of commerce,
precipitated hundreds of thousands from affluence to want, and which has done so
much to taint private and public morals" (<em>TEC</em>, p. 193). Here,
Calhoun was referring to the effects of the panic of 1837.</font>
<font size="3">Calhoun echoed Bastiat’s"legal plunder" theme
when, in an August 5, 1842, speech before the U.S. Senate regarding the proposed
tariff bill, he asked:"Protection against what? Against violence,
oppression, or fraud? If so, Government is bound to afford it.... It is the
object for which Government is instituted."</font>
<font size="3">But Calhoun saw through the protectionist charade. "No;
it [the protectionist tariff bill] is against neither violence, oppression, nor
fraud.... Against what, then, is protection asked? It is against low prices"
(<em>TEC</em>, p. 196).</font>
<font size="3">He also understood what today is considered to be a basic
principle of public-choice economics: that politicians will never give tax
dollars to special-interest groups out in the open where the public can see it
if they can disguise the looting of the taxpayers instead. The proponents of
tariff protection would never advocate having the government write checks to
manufacturing interests."No; that would be rather too open, oppressive,
and indefensible." Instead, they disguise the special-interest subsidy as
"protection," which is nothing but"tribute, levy, exaction,
monopoly, plunder..." (<em>TEC</em>, p. 197).</font>
<font size="3">Calhoun also described how artificially propping up prices in
politically favored industries with protective tariffs would cause a
misallocation of capital that would be harmful to the entire economy.</font>
<blockquote style="MARGIN-RIGHT: 0px">
<font size="3">"ncreased demand and prices consequent on the
exclusion of the article from abroad, would tempt numerous adventurers to rush
into the business, often without experience or capital; and the increased
production, in consequence, thrown into the market, would greatly accelerate
the period of renewed distress... and demand for additional protection."
(<em>TEC</em>, p. 202) </font>
<font size="3">He believed the same effect would be caused by an excessive
"expansion of the currency," which sounds a lot like an early version
of the Austrian business cycle theory.</font>
<font size="3">The senator from South Carolina expressed a version of Mises's
"middle-of-the-road-policies-lead-to-socialism" thesis: "Every
protective tariff that Congress has ever laid, has disappointed the hopes of its
advocates; and has been followed, at short intervals, by a demand for higher
duties" (<em>TEC</em>, p. 202).</font>
<font size="3">Calhoun is considered to have been perhaps the last of the
founding fathers in terms of his philosophical outlook (Joe Sobran has
persuasively argued that Lincoln, on the other hand, probably never even read <em>The
Federalist Papers</em>). Applying Madison’s theme from <em>Federalist #10</em>,
where he warns of the political destructiveness of the"violence of faction,"
Calhoun posed the rhetorical question:"Can anything be imagined more
destructive of patriotism, and more productive of faction, selfishness, and
violence, or more hostile to all economy and accountability in the
administration of the fiscal department of Government" than protectionist
tariffs? (<em>TEC</em>, p. 212). </font>
<font size="3">Protectionist tariffs would not only benefit politically
favored industries. Another major constituency, then as now, is"that
active, vigilant, and well-trained corps, which lives on Government, or expects
to live on it; which prospers most when the revenue is the greatest, the
treasury the fullest, and the expenditures the most profuse" and which will
faithfully support"whatever system shall extract most from the pockets of
the rest of the community, to be emptied into theirs" (<em>TEC</em>, p.
212). During the first 60 years of the 19th century, that
"system" was the tariff. </font>
<font size="3">He even championed unilateral free trade."If other
countries injured us by burdensome exactions, it was not reason why we should do
harm to ourselves" (Jan. 27, 1841, speech). American ingenuity and
entrepreneurship, not protectionism, were the source of the nation’s wealth,
he said in response to Henry Clay’s mercantilist superstitions. </font>
<font size="3">What, then, is to be done? How is the nation to prosper
economically? "I answer," said Calhoun in his 1842 Senate
speech,"by the reverse means proposed in order to command the home market
-- low, instead of high duties; and a sound currency." More specifically:
free trade; low duties; no debt; separation from banks; economy [in government];
retrenchment [of government expenditure]; and strict adherence to the
constitutions" (<em>TEC</em>, p. 213).</font>
<font size="3">Calhoun’s free-trade views were popular throughout the
South, and persisted after his death in 1850--so much so that on December 10,
1860, the Republican Party newspaper, the <em>Daily Chicago Times</em>, warned:
"Let the South adopt the free-trade system and the North’s commerce must
be reduced to less than half what it now is" (because of the much higher
tariff rate there). The new Confederate Constitution outlawed protectionist
tariffs altogether. </font>
<font size="3">On April 2, 1861, another Republican Party newspaper, the <em>Newark
Daily Advertiser</em>, warned ominously that Southerners had apparently
"taken to their bosoms the liberal and popular doctrine of free trade"
and that they"might be willing to go... toward free trade with the
European powers" which"must operate to the serious disadvantage of
the North" as"commerce will be largely diverted to the Southern
cities." </font>
<font size="3">"We apprehend," the New Jersey Republicans wrote,
that"the chief instigator of the present troubles -- South Carolina--have
all along for years been preparing the way for the adoption of free trade."
This, they insisted, must be avoided at all cost by"the closing of the
[Southern] ports" by military force, if necessary.</font>
<font size="3">It is telling that a little over a year earlier, in 1859, Abraham
Lincoln, a one-term congressman from Illinois, was pandering to the heavily
protectionist Pennsylvania delegation to the 1860 Republican national convention
(the state with the second highest number of electoral votes) by stating in an
October 11, 1859, letter that he was"an old Henry Clay-Tariff Whig"
and that"I made more speeches on that subject [in favor of high protective
tariffs] than any other. I have not since changed my views" (see
Reinhard Luthin,"Abraham Lincoln and the Tariff," <em>American
Historical Review</em>, July 1944). It was his reputation as perhaps the
most ardent protectionist in the Republican Party that won Lincoln the 1860
nomination and, of course, the presidency. Throughout his career, Lincoln
had adopted many of the protectionist shibboleths of Henry C. Carey, a publicist
for the Pennsylvania steel industry. </font>
<font size="3">As soon as the new Republican Party gained power, the average
tariff rate was quickly raised from a nominal 15 percent to 47 percent and
higher, and remained at such levels for decades after the war. Calhoun's
free-trade arguments, as eloquent and advanced as they were, were no match for
the federal military arsenal.</font>
<hr align="left" width="33%" SIZE="1">
<font size="2">Thomas DiLorenzo is a professor of economics in the Sellinger
School of Business and Management at Loyola College in Baltimore, and is senior
fellow of the Mises Institute. Dr. DiLorenzo is the author of <em>The
Real Lincoln: A New Look at Abraham Lincoln, His Agenda, and an Unnecessary War</em> (Forum/Random
House, 2002). See his Mises.org <font color="#000080" size="2">Articles
Archive</font>, and send him MAIL.
Also, listen to Dr. DiLorenzo's recent book discussion on The
Real Lincoln (in MP3 format).
</font>
<center>
<HR>
</center>

gesamter Thread: