- Who Benefits From Free Trade, and How / Artikel mises.org - - Elli -, 23.01.2004, 15:28
Who Benefits From Free Trade, and How / Artikel mises.org
--><div>
<font face="Verdana" size="1" color="#002864">http://www.mises.org/fullstory.asp?control=1429</font>
</div>
<div>
</div>
<div>
<font size="2"><font face="Verdana" color="#002864" size="5"><strong>Who Benefits From Free Trade, and How</strong></font>
</div>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana" size="4">by Robert P. Murphy</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">[January 23, 2004]</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana"><img alt src="http://www.mises.org/images3/corporation.gif" align="right" border="0" width="174" height="217">The
Internet has been abuzz lately with arguments over free trade. This most
recent outburst of scholarship was sparked by Sen. Charles Schumer and
economist Paul Craig Roberts' joint article in the New York Times, </font><font face="Verdana">"Second
Thoughts on Free Trade"</font><font face="Verdana">. In this article,
Roberts reiterated his position that"the case for free trade" rests
on the assumption that factors of production cannot move between countries (or
at least, cannot move as easily as final products can).</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">According to Schumer and Roberts,
in the modern world of multinational corporations, reduced shipping costs, and
high-speed telecommunications, factors of production are quite mobile indeed.
We can no longer be sure that"free trade" will work in the new
environment. Rather than David Ricardo's classical law of comparative
advantage (which showed that laborers in various countries will specialize in
those industries in which they are relatively superior), which Roberts agrees
will produce shared gains among all trading nations, in the new global economy
we confront the law of absolute advantage: Capital and labor will move to
those countries with the lowest costs of production, meaning some nations gain
and others lose.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Naturally, libertarians went
berserk over these claims. It certainly seemed as if Paul Craig Roberts were
lending scholarly justifications for raising tariffs or other barriers on
foreign imports to prevent American companies from"exporting jobs"
to low-wage nations. I myself jumped on the bandwagon of </font><font face="Verdana">criticizing
the Schumer-Roberts piece</font><font face="Verdana">, and engaged in an
email correspondence with Roberts to boot. In response to these libertarian
onslaughts, </font><font face="Verdana">Roberts
offered a blogged clarification of his position</font><font face="Verdana">.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">The present article is my attempt
at a quick response to Roberts' clarifications. Naturally this article won't
convince Roberts himself, but it may address the concerns of some who are
still on the fence (and particularly those who emailed me in response to my
linked article above).</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana"><strong>Free Trade</strong></font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">First, let's be clear what I mean
by free trade. When I say I'm"for free trade," that means I
do not think the US government should impose tariffs or other barriers (such
as import quotas) on the importation of foreign consumption goods by US
consumers. Now it's true, I'm a philosophical anti-statist and so I oppose the
very existence of the US federal government, but beyond that there are
very practical reasons for being a free trader. Specifically, I believe that
imposing tariffs makes Americans in general poorer. True, the workers in a
"protected" industry may have higher wages than they otherwise would
under free trade, but US consumers would be worse off because of higher prices.
Most economists favor free trade because (at least under classical assumptions)
when the government imposes a tariff, the monetary gains to the winners are
outweighed by the monetary losses to the losers.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Roberts says that he agrees with
this economic analysis in the case when capital goods cannot be easily shipped
from one country to another. However, Roberts argues that the benefits of
"free trade" do not necessarily hold when capital goods are
mobile internationally. In his words, this possibility means that some
countries gain and some lose.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Now here's the tricky point: I am
claiming that even if it's true that the change from immobile to mobile
factors of production"hurts" a given nation (which for a mainstream
economist means that the average real income of people in a given nation goes
down), this doesn't undermine the case for"free trade" unless we
can show that a protective tariff or other barrier on imports would mitigate
or eliminate this"hurting."</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">To use a silly analogy, it is
certainly true that an earthquake in California hurts US citizens. In other
words, Americans would be richer if there were no earthquake. But this doesn't
undermine the case for free trade, because slapping on tariffs would make
Americans even worse off. This is true even if the Americans would have
been better off with no earthquake and a small tariff.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">This is my position on free trade
and factor mobility. Even if it's true that the change from immobile to mobile
factors of production has made some countries poorer and others richer, unless
you can demonstrate to me that the losing countries could have helped
themselves by imposing tariffs, then this fact (i.e. that the change in
mobility caused pain) does not at all undermine the case for free trade. Free
trade is still the best policy. Imposing a tariff will still
make the people in the"losing" country poorer on average, relative
to how poor they would be with the change in factor mobility and free
trade.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Innovation Can
"Hurt"?</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Before continuing, let me pause to
address a certain issue. Perhaps the reader thinks I'm conceding too much to
Roberts. After all, how can it be that improved shipping technology or data
transmission can"hurt" a country? Sure, the workers in an obsolete
job might be hurt, but consumers as a whole benefit, right?</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Well, that's probably true
empirically; I for one would definitely bet that Americans in general are
richer because of, say, the Internet. But it is theoretically possible
that the average real income in a small country might be reduced because of a
technological innovation. For example, suppose that there is a small island
nation in the Pacific composed of 10,000 people. Further suppose that these
people are experts at building copy machines, and that their sole export is
copy machines sent out to people in other countries.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Now, imagine that the advent of
fax machines and email communications reduces the amount of paper copying that
needs to be done. Office workers who formerly imported paper copiers from our
hypothetical island—in order to make copies of important documents and send
them to their associates in other countries, say—now can stop buying so many
copiers. They just fax or email the relevant documents to their
associates in other countries. Thus the international demand for copiers
falls, and the 10,000 people on our hypothetical island now have to pick
bananas instead of exporting copiers. Clearly they have been"hurt"
by the improved technology.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">How does this hypothetical example
work? It concentrates the workers who are hurt by an innovation into one (imaginary)
country, and lumps all of the beneficiary consumers into the rest of the world.
Clearly average real incomes in the whole world have gone up because of
faxing and emailing; the gains to the rest of the world outweigh the losses to
the people who used to build copiers. But the point is, it's at least
conceivable that a technological innovation could on net reduce the average
real income in a given country. (For a different example, imagine if someone
invented a way to cheaply make gourmet coffee out of rocks. This might make
Brazilians poorer on average.)</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana"><strong>Tariffs No Help</strong></font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">So back to the original argument:
I'm saying that even in a case such as the one above, where an innovation
actually hurts the average person in a country, it is still the case that a
departure from free trade would have no effect at all, or would hurt this
country even more.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">In our case of the small island,
it's obvious to see that a tariff on fax machines or computers wouldn't
prevent the collapse of the domestic copier industry. It is foreign
consumers who are switching to the new products (away from paper copiers),
and so nothing the government of the small island does can stop that.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">But what about cases where it is a
country's own consumers who are switching allegiance to foreign,
low-cost producers? For example, what happens when a US manufacturer fires US
workers, physically moves his plant to Mexico, and hires Mexicans to produce
the same product, which is then imported and sold to US consumers? Isn't it
possible that a tariff on Mexican imports would prevent this, thus saving jobs?</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Yes, a tariff on Mexican imports (if
high enough) might convince the US capitalist to keep his plant in the US. But
then that means prices would be higher for US consumers—that's how the
tariff works, after all. In this case, where the consumers are located in the
country we're considering, the only way trade policy will alter the situation
is to make the consumers worse off. And as we've seen, the general rule is
that a tariff hurts consumers more than it helps producers.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">To summarize: If the benefiting
consumers from an innovation are largely outside of a given country, then it
is indeed true that the people in that country might actually be poorer as a
result of the innovation. But in that case, no trade policy can change things.
On the other hand, if enough of the benefiting consumers are inside a
particular country, then the people in that country are helped (on net)
by the innovation. Trade policy in this case can alter things (so that
the new innovation is not exploited), but in that case people on net are
poorer because of the tariff. In conclusion, no matter what the scenario,
enacting tariffs can only make people poorer on average.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana"><strong>"Who's Talking About
Tariffs?"</strong></font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">At this point, Paul Craig Roberts
would go through the roof. As he has repeatedly emphasized, he is not
arguing in favor of tariffs. All he is doing is pointing out that the case for
free trade does not hold up when factors are mobile.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">But this is why I belabored the
definition of"free trade" in this context. If Roberts agrees that
enacting tariffs or other barriers on foreign imports can never make Americans
richer—whether factors are mobile or immobile—then we can stop arguing. In
my book, this would be an admission on his part that a case (not
Ricardo's) for free trade can still be made. (It might look like the case I
made above, for example.)</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">In short, so long as Roberts
agrees with me that placing tariffs or other barriers on foreign imports won't
help Americans, then according to my definition he should stop saying he has
"second thoughts on free trade."</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana"><strong>Other Restrictions?</strong></font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">"But what about other
government measures to prevent capital outflow?" the reader might ask.
"Sure, tariffs aren't the answer—but Schumer and Roberts admit this in
their article. We need to have an honest dialogue about how to prevent the
outflow of capital goods from the US."</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">To this sort of argument, all I
can say is this: Americans are not made richer when the government imposes
artificial restrictions on the use of property. For example, if the government
taxes all exported capital goods by 50%, that will certainly reduce the
outflow of capital goods. But in these cases, one of three things will happen:</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">(1) Rather than moving
manufacturing to another country (with lower costs) and reimporting the
product to sell to American consumers at lower prices, manufacturers will now
continue to produce domestically at higher costs. So the workers in those
industries win but US consumers lose. It's the same as if the government
imposed a tariff on the reimported products.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">(2) Rather than making a good in a
foreign country (at lower costs) and selling it to other countries at a
given price, US companies will now continue to produce domestically at higher
costs and sell the product to other countries for the same given price. In
this case, the profits of US shareholders (i.e. owners of the capital goods)
will be lower. The gains of US workers will be offset by losses of US
capitalists. Now many egalitarians might like this outcome, but let's not kid
ourselves that we're making America richer by it. You could just as
well force every millionaire to pay someone $100/hour to cut his lawn and get
the same result.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">(3) Rather than shipping
manufacturing to another country (with lower costs) in order to remain
competitive in the world market, the tax on capital export might make the US
capitalists keep their capital goods in the US and devote them to another line
of production. (This is because, given US labor costs, they simply can't
compete on the world market in the original industry.) In this case, the
capital goods would have been diverted into less efficient lines of production,
and thus their rental returns would be lower. I.e., the market value of the
capital goods would drop because of the export tax. Without making ad hoc
assumptions, it is hard to see how this will make Americans in general richer.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">In conclusion, I don't believe
that other possible measures to combat the alleged problem of mobile capital
goods can help Americans in general. As with tariffs, certain groups
might benefit, but again as with tariffs, the gains of the winners will be
more than offset by the losses of the losers.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana"><strong>General Equilibrium</strong></font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">A frequent argument put forth by
Roberts runs like this: Yes, everything the libertarians say is true, taken
one at a time in a partial equilibrium context. Any given case of outsourcing
will help American consumers more than it hurts the displaced American workers.
But we can't assume that this will hold true once many industries start
moving.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Why not? Roberts has not
introduced externalities into his argument, so even on neoclassical terms why
would, say, 1000 changes all of a sudden make Americans poorer, if everyone
agrees that each change—considered one at a time—makes Americans richer?</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">The fallacy of composition works
like this: It's true that if an individual at a football game stands up, he
can see the game better. But if everyone stands up, nobody can see any
better.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">But this doesn't apply in the
present case. If Roberts agrees that when Industry X outsources to Asia, US
consumers benefit more than US workers lose, and if Roberts agrees that the
same holds for Industries Y, Z, etc., then it's also true (without any further
arguments about externalities) that even on neoclassical grounds, when all of
these industries outsource, US consumers benefit more than US workers lose.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Now of course, the obvious retort
will be: What happens when all of our industries are outsourced!! Then
we'll be a nation of unemployed beggars, unable to afford any imports no
matter how cheap!</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">But wait a second. If it's true
that after Industries A, B, C, D, …, and Z outsource, then Americans are
poorer than if all of those industries had remained in the US, then it must be
true (again, without an argument concerning externalities that Roberts
certainly hasn't advanced) that at some point, the outsourcing of a particular
industry made Americans poorer on average. Let's say it's Industry J. So in
other words, Roberts has been backed into a corner arguing, ‘It's fine if
Industries A through I move to Asia, but after that America would have been
better off if Industries J through Z remained in the US.'</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">If this is indeed true, then guess
what? That's exactly what will happen on the free market. Manufacturing
operations will continue to move to other countries until that point at which
it is no longer efficient for them to do so. And along the way to this point,
each step (as Roberts concedes) makes Americans on net wealthier, so that
means the whole process makes Americans a lot wealthier (on net)
than if we tried to prevent the outsourcing in the first place.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">(To understand what would prevent
the outsourcing at some point, keep in mind that"cheap" foreign
labor would no longer be so cheap after nominal wages changed and/or exchange
rates changed in response to the continual outsourcing. Yes, the actual dollar
amount of the average American's salary might be lower, but his standard of
living would be higher because of all the new, cheap imports due to
outsourcing.)</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana"><strong>Sundry</strong></font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Before I wrap up this behemoth of
an article, let me address three final issues. One is this: If somebody wants
to up and leave the US because he or she perceives a better life elsewhere,
then of course in this sense increased mobility might make the US
poorer. For example, if Bill Gates all of a sudden says,"I'm going to
move to Hong Kong because now it's pretty easy to ship my favorite mansion
over there," then his exit would lower the average income of (remaining)
US citizens. If this is all people are talking about, then fine. In
this type of case, I would of course say that a person's liberty to leave the
country should not be sacrificed to the goal of propping up a statistical
figure.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Another issue is slavery. People
email me and say,"Your theories would be true if everyone had a free
market, but China employs slave labor."</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Okay, this is a valid point. If
you don't want to indirectly encourage slave labor, then by all means, don't
buy products that may have been produced under not entirely voluntary
circumstances. All I'm claiming here, though, is that don't kid yourself that
you're making yourself wealthier by doing so. If you choose to buy a
product from a US firm for $10 that you could import from Asia for $5, then
you're down $5 on the decision. Of course, maybe that's what you want to do;
more power to you. But don't think you're making America"richer,"
and don't run to the government to force your decision on the rest of us.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Finally, let me concede that the
above arguments are not rigorous enough for publication in a mainstream
economics journal. Paul Craig Roberts has repeatedly claimed that libertarians
are arguing with"economic theory" and not him per se. He has even
said that if we're right, then we should publish our case and win the Nobel
Prize.</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Well, I don't know enough about
modern trade theory to evaluate his claims. But if it turns out that a
mathematical model based on the above musings is worthy of a Nobel... hey,
I could use a million bucks. (You know how many TVs you can import with that
kind of money?)</font>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><span class="833100714-23012004"><font face="Verdana">_____________________________</font></span>
<p class="MsoBodyText"><font face="Verdana">Robert Murphy is an adjunct
scholar of the Mises Institute and the Mackinac Center for Public Policy in
Midland, Michigan. He teaches economics at <ST1:PLACE>
<ST1:PLACENAME>
Hillsdale</ST1:PLACENAME>
<ST1:PLACETYPE>
College</ST1:PLACETYPE>
</ST1:PLACE>
. </font><font face="Verdana">robert_p_murphy@yahoo.com</font><font face="Verdana">.
See the </font><font face="Verdana">Murphy
Archive</font><font face="Verdana">.</font>
</font>

gesamter Thread: